Greece's dramatic
bailout negotiations will soon be coming to a head one way or the other.
Although the Greek government has been painstakingly throwing a veil of
uncertainty and misinformation over its real financial and fiscal position,
most pundits would agree that state coffers are running bare and that, absent
an interim, piece-meal, or final bailout agreement, Greece will not be able to
pay off the consolidated IMF loan tranches coming up at the end of June. The
government's finances have been stretched to their limit by dint of an internal
payment moratorium and a raid on the cash reserves of local governments and
pension funds.
The Syriza government's
bargaining strategy has been one of ‘coercive deficiency’ (a term coined by
political economist and historian Lucius Wilmerding, Jr. and further qualified
by game theorist Thomas Schelling), ‘creative ambiguity’ (another notorious
expression reintroduced into the political vocabulary by Greek Finance Minister
Yanis Varoufakis), and politicisation.
Prime Minister Alexis
Tsipras and his party clearly interpreted the outcome of the January 2015
elections as a strong popular mandate for the implementation of the party's
‘Thessaloniki’ electoral programme without jeopardising the country's position
in the EMU. They, therefore, decided to gamble much of their political capital
on an aggressive high-risk strategic posture in the renegotiation of the
existing bailout programme. In practice, this meant that the government was
willing to engage in a protracted and precarious game of attrition with its
creditors patiently waiting out for a palatable compromise solution that would
not flagrantly violate any of the party's ‘red lines’ and that would set the
economy back on the path of debt sustainability and economic growth.
According to the logic
of ‘coercive deficiency’, a debtor’s (economic) weakness is (bargaining)
strength vis-à-vis its creditors. The weaker the economy appears to be, the
lower are the primary surplus targets to which he can credibly commit. Yet,
this protracted period of economic uncertainty, marked by a freeze-out on
public and private payments and a ballooning of the government’s arrears, has brought
the Greek economy back on its knees by draining the liquidity out of the
system. Growth levels are back into negative territory, tax revenues are once
again plummeting, and unemployment levels are back on an upward trend.
Clearly, Tsipras’
high-risk political gamble is that he can keep riding his soaring waves of
popularity through these rough waters of economic downturn until he achieves a
favourable negotiation outcome. Recent polls seem to confirm his assessment as
the Greek people have shown remarkable signs of resilience and cool all things
considered. With regard to this inescapable trade-off between the attainment of
a less austere and front-loaded bailout programme and the acute economic costs
of a bargaining standoff in terms of overall economic activity, the Syriza
coalition government has made a clear choice to safeguard the disposable income
and pensions of its core supporters in the public sector and the salaried
middle class at the expense of the beleaguered private sector.
The tenet of ‘creative
ambiguity’, which has been openly proclaimed as a key feature of the Greek
government’s bargaining posture, is closely wedded to the latter’s attempt to
politicise the bailout negotiations to the highest degree possible. ‘Creative
ambiguity’ might be employed in a negotiation both to disguise the distance in
the negotiating parties’ position on a contentious issue and to do so in a
manner that enables each to claim a favourable agreement.
In the case of the
Greek bailout, it refers to the application of flexible fiscal rules and
targets achievable by a home-grown and politically feasible mix of fiscal
consolidation and structural reforms. The politicisation of the bailout
negotiations refers both to the choice of European summitry as the appropriate
institutional arena for an ultimate political solution, but also the attempt to
avert the imposition of wide-ranging hard conditionality arrangements enforced
by self-serving and unaccountable supranational bureaucrats (namely, the
‘troika’ or ‘institutions’). In effect, this strategy dovetails well with the
new government’s avowed electoral mandate to regain ownership of the country’s
reform strategy and growth plan.
The politicisation of
the Greek bailout negotiations also entails the pronouncement of the country’s
geopolitical salience as a member of the EU, EMU, and NATO, and the systemic
ripple effects of a potential Greek default. If successfully done, this can be
a winning strategy for Greece as it seeks to enlist the support of major economic
powers outside of the EU (namely Russia and the US) and thus to exploit the
preference heterogeneity among its creditors.
Research done by IMF
scholars has shown that systemically and geopolitically important countries
under external financial strain (e.g. Mexico in 1995) tend to receive higher
loans with less intrusive conditionality attached to them. In other words, when
the core interests of major creditor countries are at stake, they assume
‘temporary control’ of the decision-making process of international financial
institutions (notably the IMF) in order to ensure favourable treatment for
their valued ‘client’ states and allies. However, under certain conditions, the
preference heterogeneity among the multiple principals of a debtor country may
allow supranational bureaucrats to exploit ‘agency slack’, further their
autonomy, and reaffirm their raison d'être by means of more intrusive
conditionality arrangements.
Therefore, from the
point of view of Greece’s creditors, there are more objectives to consider in
the design of another Greek bailout other than the pursuit of the country’s
debt sustainability. Greece is a financially strained country that is also a
member of a monetary union with fuzzy and weakly enforced rules. To be sure,
German Chancellor Angela Merkel insisted on the participation of the IMF in the
original Greek bailout in 2010 in order to complement the EMU’s porous
enforcement mechanisms.
In economic terms, the
size of the Greek economy (comprising around 2 per cent of the euro area’s GDP)
does not justify all the fuss and global media attention surrounding this
crisis. In political terms, however, the stakes are much higher, since whatever
shape the final resolution of the Greek problem takes (either through another
bailout, Grexit, or some other solution) will constitute a bellwether for the
evolution of EMU rules and governance structures.
Eurozone officials
keep stating that Greece should not be accorded favourable treatment vis-à-vis
the other indebted economies of the European South that have also had to
implement similar austerity programmes under explicit memoranda of
understanding (e.g. Portugal and Ireland) or softer conditionality arrangements
(e.g. Spain and Italy). Yet, in the case of Greece a growing number of
economists have been arguing that this unwavering adherence to fixed rules
based on erroneous parametric estimates has further exacerbated the depth of
the depression to levels unprecedented during peace times (estimated at a 25
per cent loss of GDP in five years).
The problem that
Eurozone officials are now facing is how to inject more flexibility into a new
Greek bailout programme without giving the appearance of undermining the
existing framework of fiscal rules within the Eurozone. The traditional
trade-off between moral hazard, or in this case the misaligned incentive for
fiscal profligacy in anticipation of a bailout, and a country’s need for
liquidity in order to service its debt may, in the context of the EMU, only be
overcome through further fiscal coordination and political integration. Despite
early steps in that direction (with the Fiscal Compact and the ‘six-pack’),
Germany and the bloc of like-minded countries have adopted an unsustainable
strategy of ‘muddling through’, whilst cherishing in the meantime the short-run
economic benefits of a weak euro and negative interest rates.
Both EU consensual
politics and the fear of uncertainty over the effects of a potential Grexit
would dictate that some type of agreement will emerge in the Greek case after
months of strategic posturing and political brinkmanship. It remains to be seen
whether such an agreement will require the guaranteed support of centrist
pro-European opposition parties in the Greek Parliament (such as Potami, Pasok,
and even New Democracy) in order to be ratified. If that is the case, Tsipras
will have no other choice but to call snap elections with unpredictable
repercussions for the country’s political and economic stability or attempt to
form a unity government.
In order to tame
Syriza’s rebellious left-wing factions, Tsipras may well threaten to avail
himself of a useful constitutional weapon at his disposal, namely the fact that
he would have full control over the drafting of closed electoral lists in a
potential election contest following the dissolution of a
less-than-one-year-old parliament. After all, we should not forget that Syriza,
a former coalition of left-wing factions and social movements, only recently
acquired the legal status of a unitary liberal democratic party in order to be
eligible for the 50-seat electoral bonus accorded to the party with the highest
vote share in the run-up to the January 2015 elections.
The Greek saga has been
a nail-biting story of enormous political complexity featuring epic battles
between markets and politicians, technocracy and democracy, supranationalism
and intergovernmentalism, populism and mainstream politics. It was a
politically motivated decision to let Greece into the euro, it will take a
mighty political compromise on many different levels to keep it in. Unlike
ancient Greek tragedies, the unravelling plot of this modern Greek drama is
still in the hands of its main protagonists.
Nikitas Konstantinidis, University
Lecturer in International Political Economy University
of Cambridge, Department of Politics and International Studies.
Published also here.
Published also here.
No comments:
Post a Comment