Reform
proposals in 2016 were structured around implementing common rules. Consolidation
was to operate in three dimensions: Across generations, across occupational
categories (i.e. between wage employees and the rest) and in administrative
structures. Those proposals repeated the key idea of a detailed 1957 policy paper, written by the
mother of an Economy Minister of the late 1990s: “There is
urgent need of a system … free of the unacceptable position that its objective
is to secure privileges of the few against the many, which will use the
available means to meet needs”.
(quoted in Tinios 2010).
That blueprint, also built around consolidation, was to have been implemented in 1958. However, the impending elections postponed it. The same reform was also postponed in the following decades:
That blueprint, also built around consolidation, was to have been implemented in 1958. However, the impending elections postponed it. The same reform was also postponed in the following decades:
- In 1968 due to the dictatorship.
- In 1978 due to inflation.
- In 1988 the reform was leaked to the press and then abandoned.
- In 1998 the ‘Spraos report’ provoked hostile reactions.
- In 2008 a cosmetic law could not avert bankruptcy a year later.
- In 2018 is the prospective date of full implementation of the 2016 proposals.
I try to
elucidate this question by means of three diagrams.
Diagram 1: How to miss the point
Advanced
countries over the last half-century have been engaged in three generations or phases of pension discussion, each examining
the issue in a context where different issues were paramount. The initial
phase dealt with the establishment and spread of social protection and favoured
large, state-run systems. From the
1980s, the mature or intermediate phase focused on ageing, attempting to broaden the
range of societal actors called to meet the challenge. From 2000 on, pension discussions are trying
to encompass challenges arising from the nature of work and from globalization.
The response is greater flexibility Schema A tries to summarise the three types
of discussion:
The Greek pension system was overwhelmed by the original 1950s ‘question set’, having got stuck on how to combat fragmentation, both in institutions and in insurance arrangements and how to ensure common rules. Fixed on this, Greek society did not realise that the world had moved on. The out of date framing of the question affected the type of reform that was finally passed after the crisis erupted in 2010. This can be seen in the fact that, even the ‘new system’ introduced in 2010 and completed in 2016 was still a 1960s-style, large, State-run, PAYG system. Where the whole of pension provision remained exclusively the preserve of the State.
The Greek pension system was overwhelmed by the original 1950s ‘question set’, having got stuck on how to combat fragmentation, both in institutions and in insurance arrangements and how to ensure common rules. Fixed on this, Greek society did not realise that the world had moved on. The out of date framing of the question affected the type of reform that was finally passed after the crisis erupted in 2010. This can be seen in the fact that, even the ‘new system’ introduced in 2010 and completed in 2016 was still a 1960s-style, large, State-run, PAYG system. Where the whole of pension provision remained exclusively the preserve of the State.
Diagram 2: The content of discussion: wrong solutions to the wrong problem
There was considerable
policy activism on pensions after 2010. If the problem before the crisis was
procrastination and inactivity, 2010 appears as a watershed, when things were
finally dealt with. What, before the crisis was talk without action, was
replaced by action without talk. Was this change sufficient to correct the
problems spotted in the previous section?
Unfortunately,
Diagram B catalogues that the type of mechanisms which neutralized the capacity
of public discussion to spot and correct underlying problems. A combination of
misinformation – such as discontinuing statistics, avoidance of discussion,
blame avoidance and misrepresentation meant that wrong solutions kept being
offered to a problem which was, in any case, misidentified. An example is the
repeated use, starting from the Prime Minister and going on to Oxford-educated
ministers, of the nonsense argument: “pensions should not be cut, as
grandparents give pocketmoney to their unemployed grandchildren”. Even if such a statement were factually
correct, it misses two key policy points: (a) It is employed grandchildren that
pay for grandparents’ pensions. (b) Why not give benefits directly to grandchildren?
Passing the can down the road, was hardly new. There was, however a key difference which was not grasped: Developments in the economic and social environment had accelerated and were, by 2015, dramatically different. Assurances of pension system viability were followed within weeks by a new set of cuts. The pension system was no longer trusted to play its key role – to guarantee income security at old age.
Hiding
behind the smokescreen of the new-style blame avoidance, a vicious circle
remained in continuous operation. The delegitimation of public pensions
proceeded unchecked. Halting this race
to the bottom needed to win back trust from the insured population. As time
went on this could only be done by
turning a new leaf: an entirely new system. Such a reform however was prevented
from happening. The final diagram asks why.
Diagram 3: How to avoid a fresh start.
A complete
change of system is always a leap into the unknown. This is certainly so for
providers, but even more so for the insured population. They need to tear up
the familiar contract to replace it with something unknown and, indeed,
unknowable.
Winning the
trust of the population for such a leap is the real task of reform. To turn a
new leaf, it is not enough simply to point out to problems, or even to produce
a shining new technocratic blueprint.
Technocratic insights must be communicated
so that people understand both why the existing situation is problematic
and how proposals are superior. In the case of pensions, discussions has to go
through an equivalent process: Studies or actuarial reviews point out problems;
public debate translates them so that every person understands what the
problems mean for their own particular circumstances. Tinkering within the
parameters of the familiar, existing system needs to be shown as insufficient,
before the big step of a totally new system is finally implemented.
The question of discontinuous regime change in the social sciences has been most extensively discussed in the context of revolutionary political change (for obvious reasons). In contrast with neclassical economics and bourgeois sociology which focus on gradual change, the Leninist theory asks what needs to happen for a complete overhaul – arguably what needs to happen for a fresh start in Greek pensions.
The problem in Greece, was that the political process that should have led to reform is blocked:
·
Technocratic exercises on pensions are heavily
discouraged. No independent research body on ageing exists, while research on
pensions receives little encouragement. Reform proposals are seldom discussed,
while indiscriminate labelling of reformist views as ‘neoliberal’, ensures they
don’t get a hearing.
·
Unorthodox opinions are subject to heavy
bullying by the media: The messenger is blamed for the message, often subjected
to personal attacks and invective. This applies both to technocrats and to
politicians, who both risk to find themselves in the political wilderness.
So, despite
a crying need for a refounding of the system, systemic change did not take root
– neither before or during the crisis.
There was an absence of both reforms
– in the sense of fully explained package – but also of reformers – in the sense of politicians prepared to risk their
reputations advocating reform.
Conclusion: A failure of pension reform technology
My argument
had six steps:
1. The Greek pension system was never
able to correct its ‘original sin’: fragmentation and application of general
rules.
2. As a consequence, it missed the fact
that the world had changed, and with it, the characteristics of a pension
system appropriate to the 21st century.
3. Even after 2010, the troika only
began putting in place a revamped 1960s PAYG statist system.
4. The mechanisms of postponement
continue to operate after 2010 in a slightly changed form, built around blame
avoidance.
5. The need for a fresh start is
repeatedly missed. The system sinks in a spiral of ever deeper mistrust.
6. The reform technology available
was unable to deliver even minor
parametric reforms
A French
politician is said to have remarked that “he had never encountered a problem
whose non-solution was not, itself, a solution”. This was faithfully
implemented in Greek pensions. As a result, the 2016 reform carried the seeds
of its own failure by the very process that led to its adoption: The new system
given the discussion that preceded could not help but being:
· Monolithically state run - by 100%
· Too generous
· Too inflexible.
As such it Shifts
more of the burden onto next generation and onto production; it creates a
'hole' of insufficient coverage for 40-year olds who will not have enough time
to make alternative provisions; it pretends that today’s low pension pensioners
can remain unaffected, even after the
review that is take place in 2018. As a result the new pension system fits into
a zero-sum strategy of redistribution, which is to take place both between generations
and between income groups.
Pension
reform is the ‘mother of all reforms’, certainly in the sense of having been in
the cards for longest but also because of the importance acknowledged by
domestic actors. The vicissitudes of pension reform can lead to a number of
take-home points for reform in general:
· Process can
overtake content, especially if
the reform is drawn out. It is hard to
keep one’s ‘eye on the ball’, which needs to be the benefits of reform.
· When reform becomes an end in
itself, it may end up being counterproductive
· In Post truth politics it is easier to demolish rather than to build.
· Civil society is enormously
important. The integrity of the policy discussion community can make the
difference between success and failure.
Finally, what has happened to Greek pensions could be generalized to any
number of serious attempts to change things.
Dr Platon Tinios, Assistant Professor, Piraeus University
A longer version of this piece can be found in Tinios, P. , The Greek pension Tragedy: A case of failure in Governance, Konrad Adenauer Stiftung, KAS-katoptron, http://www.kas.de/wf/doc/kas_44877-1522-2-30.pdf?160414150400
Dr Platon Tinios, Assistant Professor, Piraeus University
A longer version of this piece can be found in Tinios, P. , The Greek pension Tragedy: A case of failure in Governance, Konrad Adenauer Stiftung, KAS-katoptron, http://www.kas.de/wf/doc/kas_44877-1522-2-30.pdf?160414150400
No comments:
Post a Comment